In the aftermath of
the 2008 global economic crisis, governments around the world adopted new
capitalization requirements for financial institutions. Known as Basel III,
these regulations have been sold as a way to strengthen shock absorption in the
banking industry, to improve its risk management and enhance transparency.
However, just like
most government regulations, Basel III comes with unintended, and potentially
catastrophic, consequences. At the heart of the problem is the new structure of
capitalization requirements that give strong preferential treatment to
government debt – regardless of its credit rating.
The core of the
problem is that financial institutions do not need the same rate of own capital
in purchasing bonds from governments as they do for buying private equity. The
lower capitalization rates apply to government bonds generally with at least
AA- rating.
The big can of worms
is opened by the proviso saying that banks can buy domestic-government debt at
any credit rating, with less own capital than if they buy prime-credit private
equity.
On the face of it,
this does not seem to be a problem. Historically, government bonds have been a
very safe low-risk anchor for any investment strategy; if the Basel III
requirements had been introduced in, say, the 1990s they would not have been no
cause for concern.
However, given the
experience from the crisis that broke out in 2008 put these regulations in a
new light.
Starting in 2009, banks experienced dwindling loan demand
from non-financial businesses. Default risks increased (as is always the case
during a recession) growing the need for low-risk government bonds. However,
Europe’s treasury bond market offered a narrowing window of low-risk
opportunities. A growing share of it was drifting into high-risk waters, with
numerous credit downgrades across Europe. Financial institutions increased
their ownership of downgraded government debt by 55 percent in a four-year period,
2009-2013.
- In April 2009 Moody’s put the Irish government on downgrade watch, executing the first of a total of five downgrades three months later. That same year the Irish government added 24.6 billion euros to its debt, and financial institutions bought 78 percent of that new debt.
- In 2010, when Fitch added two Irish downgrades to those by Moody’s, the Dublin government borrowed 39.5 billion euros. Financial institutions purchased 59 percent of it.
- By 2011, when Standard & Poor put Ireland on yet another downgrade watch, financial institutions stabilized their ownership of Irish debt. However, the pattern from Ireland was repeated in Spain. In June 2010 Moody’s put Spain on downgrade watch. In the following two years they downgraded the Spanish government’s credit rating five times. During that time the Spanish government borrowed 323 billion euros, of which financial institutions picked up 71 percent.
- This amount, 230 billion, was more than three times as much as financial institutions had invested in Spanish debt over the seven years preceding 2009.
- Portugal went on Moody’s downgrade watch in May 2010, followed by a downgrade in July that year. Another four downgrades took place in the following 18 months. Despite its declining credit rating, in 2010-2012 the government in Lisbon was able to borrow another 64 billion euros. Financial institutions bought 55 percent of the new debt.
- Italy was put on downgrade watch in June 2011. In the following 12 months the country was hit by three downgrades; while Italy’s credit went into tailspin, financial institutions purchased 203.5 billion euros worth of Italian government debt – 66 billion euros more than what the government needed to borrow.
In four of the five most credit-challenged countries in
Europe, financial institutions bought massive amounts of treasury bonds right
as the crisis escalated. It is important to note, though, that this level of
data is not available for Greece, the most troubled government in Europe. What
is well known, though, is the Greek debt write-off in 2012 where investors lost
one quarter of their money with the stroke of a pen.
Purchases of weak-credit government debt was not limited to
Ireland, Portugal, Spain, Italy and Greece. France lost its AAA rating with
Standard & Poor in January 2012. In November that year Moody’s downgraded
France, followed by Fitch in July of 2013 and yet another downgrade by S&P
in November 2013. In 2010-2012 the French government borrowed 341 billion
euros, of which financial institutions bought 44 percent, or 150 billion euros.
But not only that: the financial-institution share of the
debt purchases actually accelerated as France came closer to a downgrade. They
bought:
- 16.3 percent of new French debt in 2010,
- 45.6 percent in 2011, and
- 66.5 percent in 2012.
The investments in downgraded government debt reviewed here
took place before the Basel III requirements went into effect. It is relevant
to ask how much more debt from these governments that banks would have bought
had Basel III been in place in 2008.
This is not just a hypothetical question. A new economic
crisis will come, and it will lead to major expansions in government debt.
Among the governments that will increase borrowing are the ones mentioned here,
most of which have not recovered their credit rating. This means that treasury
bonds with AA- or higher credit are more scarce now, relatively speaking, than
before 2008. Therefore, in response to the capitalization bias in Basel III, financial
institutions will prioritize domestic government debt, even if its credit is
rated far below AAA.
The obvious question is what will happen to banks with major
investments in low-credit domestic government debt. While government defaults
are rare, the Greek debt write-down has opened for possible future losses to
bank portfolios that were unthinkable only 10-15 years ago.
Two factors exacerbate the problem. The first one is the “flip
side” of the domestic debt incentive. While constructed to motivate banks to
buy domestic public debt, it also reinforces the incentive to governments to
use deficits as a permanent method for funding expenditures. Since they know that
their domestic banks are skewed – by government regulations – to buy up their
debt regardless of credit status, they are much less inclined to restrain
spending. At least in theory, this could lead to a situation where governments
calculate on deficits as a permanent source of funding spending.
Secondly, the Basel III capitalization regulations could
lead to the perpetuation of irresponsible monetary policy. During the economic
crisis European monetary policy became focused
on quantity management, supplying low-cost loans to financial institutions in
return for investments in downgraded government debt. This led financial
institutions to abandon risk aversion for risk neutrality. Over a longer period
of time, lax monetary policy over-supplies the economy with liquidity, perpetuates
low-to-negative interest rates and, in addition to neutralizing government-debt
risk, leads to excessive liquidity supply to financial and real estate markets.
In conclusion, the effects of Basel III regulations of bond
investments could be a destabilization of the very financial system the
regulations are created to stabilize. Consistent with Austrian economic theory,
over-supply of liquidity leads to asset-price spirals inconsistent with real
economic activity. If we add to this the neutralization of risk assessment of
government spending, there is a strong case for a destabilization of multiple
national economies in Europe, not limited to the financial system. With
governments being able to spend on borrowed money, impervious to their credit
rating, the negative macroeconomic effects of government spending will add to a
destabilized financial system.
Much of this reasoning remains theoretical as the combined
effects of Basel III have yet to be tried in a real-life economy.
However, evidence from the latest economic crisis, from economic theory and from the prevailing negative experience of long-term growth in government spending, all suggest,
in isolation, that the combination of the three presents the
industrialized world with a potentially catastrophic scenario for the next
economic crisis.
For this reason the world should be fearful of the combined effects of Basel III, both on individual nations and on the global economy.
No comments:
Post a Comment