Ask any mainstream, modern economist about Keynes and his
contributions to economics, and chances are you will be told that “he’s the guy
who said you should expand government in recessions”. This is such a
well-established story that the very question in itself would motivate the
economist to raise an eyebrow or two and carefully examine you for signs of
delusion.
Depending on political leaning, economists will either say
that Keynes was a socialist/statist (conservatives, libertarians) or a liberal
(socialists, statists). Both will agree,
though, that Keynes’s contributions were all about expanding government.
Austrian economists, who are often libertarian by political leaning, will
confidently say that their theory is the one that preserves limited government
and free markets. In fact, most economists would habitually tell you that
Austrian economics is the free-market theory and Keynesian economics is the
“grow government” theory.
Few, if any, of those who pass confident judgments on
Keynesian economics have ever read anything by Keynes’s hand. When I actually
began studying The General Theory of
Employment, Interest and Money as a freshly baked BA with a major in
economics (and philosophy), I soon found out that an astounding number of professors
at the department where I got my degree considered the General Theory “unreadable”. I, for one, thought it was fascinating
- though admittedly it took me until I was halfway through graduate school
before I felt that I had a reasonable command of the book’s content.
Which goes toward making my point. Keynes, like Hayek, Hicks,
Pigou and other economists who laid the groundwork of the discipline in the
early 20th century, did not start their reasoning with “consider lemma”. They
began with real-world problems and then applied whatever methodology was
appropriate for the problem. To someone who is trained entirely, or even
predominantly, in technical economics of the past 25-30 years, Keynes’s
approach to problem-oriented reasoning can indeed seem inaccessible.
Arrogantly, many of my contemporary graduate students
dismissed this old-fashioned approach to scholarly work as “history of economic
thought”.
As we will see in a later article, this arrogance has come
home to the economics departments to roost.
Back to Keynes. The fascinating thing about Keynes is that he
took on problems that, essentially, had been left untouched by others. As his
scholarly career progressed, those problems tended to become more and more
systemic in nature, culminating with the General
Theory. I do not wish to spoil the plot of the book for those of you who
have not yet read it, but let me put it this way: it is not a book about how to
expand government in recessions.
It is not even a book about recessions or the business cycle.
It is a book about the interaction between uncertainty and
macroeconomic activity.
Sounds weird? Probably, and that is not your fault. If you
have any economics on your resume, you have most likely been served basic
macroeconomics that can be captured in the IS-LM general equilibrium model. You
have possibly studied a number of aspects of “sticky prices” which, you were
told, can explain why the economy is not operating at full employment.
Some of you may have studied labor-market economics and
browsed through theories of search costs, insiders vs. outsiders and maybe even
a dollop of NAIRU.
If you have learned about Keynes, you were probably told -
again - that he proposed growing government. You may also have encountered
suggestions that Keynes thought “sticky prices” explained unemployment.
All of that belongs in the conventional-wisdom bucket. At no
point, though, does uncertainty enter the picture.
The best way to explain Keynes’s use of uncertainty is to
start with a quote from Chapter 16, also known as Sundry Observations on the Nature of Capital:
An act of individual saving means—so to
speak—a decision not to have dinner to-day. But it does not necessitate a
decision to have dinner or to buy a pair of boots a week hence or a year hence
or to consume any specified thing at any specified date. Thus it depresses the
business of preparing to-day's dinner without stimulating the business of
making ready for some future act of consumption. It is not a substitution of
future consumption-demand for present consumption-demand,—it is a net
diminution of such demand. Moreover, the expectation of future consumption is
so largely based on current experience of present consumption that a reduction
in the latter is likely to depress the former, with the result that the act of
saving will not merely depress the price of consumption-goods and leave the
marginal efficiency of existing capital unaffected, but may actually tend to
depress the latter also. In this event it may reduce present investment-demand
as well as present consumption-demand.
Do you see the key point here? When consumer
spending declines today, revenue tightens for businesses. As revenue gets
tighter, businesses scramble to find any reason to believe that sales will pick
up in the foreseeable future. Keynes makes the point that his decision not to
buy a pair of boots today does not constitute a promise to come in tomorrow, or
next week, and buy that pair of boots.
The consumer may or may not come back; the
point is that no one, probably not even the consumer, knows when he will make
that spending decision. All that we know for sure, so to speak, is that the
decline in consumer spending today has made the future of the shoe store in
question more uncertain.
Herein lies an essential element of Keynes’s contribution to
macroeconomics. At the time when he began writing macroeconomics the prevailing
wisdom was that when consumer spending declines the prices of consumer products
would decline fast enough to motivate consumers to resume spending in the
“short run”. Keynes, on the other hand, makes the point that prices can fall
all they want - it does not mean that consumers feel confident enough to go out
and increase spending again.
Part of the controversy between Keynes’s predecessors is a
controversy over what side of the economy, supply or demand, drives economic
activity. Those faithful to pre-Keynesian economics would say that supply
always creates its own demand (a.k.a., Say’s law). When there is excess supply
- as in the case with the non-purchased boots - supply will create its own
demand through declining product prices.
By contrast, Keynes stated that a decline in demand could not
necessarily be countered with a decline in the price of that product. First of
all, nothing says that the decline in price will make the consumer better off;
for all we know his income could have fallen even more rapidly. In that case
the pair of boots have, relatively speaking, become more expensive.
He does not even have to be facing a reduction in his real
wage; maybe his employer has just been purchased in a hostile takeover and he
has no idea what employment security he can count on. Or maybe the news this
morning was full of surprisingly bad economic forecasts.
In other words: uncertainty injects itself between the
consumer and the pair of boots he was considering buying.
So long as consumers feel uncertain about the future they
will not go out and spend money. Keynes’s contribution was to analyze the systemic,
macroeconomic effects of uncertainty on a macroeconomic scale. When it gets
strong enough, and widespread enough, there is no telling how deeply into a
recession, or a depression, the economy can sink.
Said Keynes. Then he spent a good part of the book analyzing
the conditions under which the economy can recover again. But that is a
different story, one we will have to get back to.
That's all for now. If you want to know more about uncertainty and macroeconomic stability, check out my dissertation which was published by Ashgate (now part of Rutledge) in 2002.
No comments:
Post a Comment